查了一下,造成自2020年以后通胀的原因是

加州阳光123
楼主 (文学城)

https://www.bls.gov/opub/mlr/2023/beyond-bls/what-caused-inflation-to-spike-after-2020.htm

January 2023

What caused inflation to spike after 2020?

Summary written by: Richard Hernandez

The United States was experiencing a period of low inflation before 2020. Then, in early 2020, the coronavirus disease 2019 (COVID-19) created various market problems, causing prices for goods and services to rise. In “Understanding U.S. inflation during the COVID era” (National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 30613, October 2022), Laurence M. Ball, Daniel Leigh, and Prachi Mishra conduct indepth research to address the questions, What has caused U.S. inflation to rise since 2020, and where is it headed?

To answer these questions, the authors break down the headline inflation number into two categories: core inflation and deviations from the core inflation number. Core inflation is the level of slack or tightness in the labor market. Deviations from the core inflation number are the large changes in the price of a good or service in a particular industry. These deviations can also be unexpected inflation shocks to the headline inflation figure. These shocks can then lead to a pass-through inflation increase to core inflation.

As the labor market tightened during 2021 and 2022, core inflation rose as the ratio of job vacancies to unemployment increased. This ratio is used to measure wage pressures that then pass through to the prices for goods and services. As workers bargain for better pay, firms begin to increase prices. So, from this research, the authors find that three main components explain the rise in inflation since 2020: volatility of energy prices, backlogs of work orders for goods and service caused by supply chain issues due to COVID-19, and price changes in the auto-related industries.

To answer the question of where inflation is headed, the authors point to two factors: the relationship between vacancies and unemployment and long-term inflation expectations, because the Federal Reserve tames inflation by increasing interest rates. The authors forecast the December 2024 inflation level to range from 2.3 to 4.8 percent.

Ball and colleagues conclude that the rise in the ratio of job vacancies to unemployment contributed almost a third of the rise in core inflation of 2.0 percentage points over a 12-month period. The 2.0-percentage-point increase in inflation explains about half the rise in core inflation, climbing from 2.3 to 6.9 percent (total increase of 4.6 percentage points). And finally, they found that the main contributors to the headline inflation shocks were energy prices (2.7 percentage points) and a backlog of work (1.7 percentage points).

加州阳光123
另一篇:

https://insights.som.yale.edu/insights/what-did-the-last-four-years-teach-us-about-managing-inflation

What Did the Last Four Years Teach Us about Managing Inflation?

Central banks around the world have faced years of extraordinary circumstances, including the COVID-related crash of the global economy, a spike in inflation, and an ensuing runup in interest rates. William English, Eugene F. Williams, Jr. Professor of the Practice and a former economist at the Federal Reserve, discusses the lessons learned and what still stands in the way of a soft landing.

 

Photo: Frederic J. Brown/AFP via Getty Images William B. English Eugene F. Williams, Jr. Professor of the Practice of Finance Interview conducted and edited by Ted O’Callahan April 22, 2024

Q: There’s tremendous attention on inflation these days. But the Federal Reserve and other central banks have been dealing with extraordinary circumstances for more than four years. Would you walk us through the challenges, the responses, and what we have learned, starting with the shutdown from the COVID pandemic?

While “unprecedented” is a term that can be overused, when the pandemic hit in 2020, it was an unprecedented shock. It had been 100 years since we’d had a global pandemic. And, of course, we now have a much bigger, much more complicated, much more integrated global economy, which was abruptly shut down.

It was very hard for policymakers to understand what was happening and to judge what was the right thing to do. Central banks did basically everything in their power to help get their economies going again. They have three monetary policy levers: interest rates, balance sheets, and guidance. They used them all to respond powerfully and quickly.

Q: How were the tools used?

In the U.S. interest rates were cut to zero. There were big rate cuts in many other countries, if there was space to cut.

Central banks also used their balance sheets. They bought a lot of securities to improve the functioning of markets that were really dislocated by the size of the pandemic shock and the uncertainty around it, and subsequently to push down longer-term rates and ease financial conditions.

By the fall of 2021, it was clear inflation was lasting. Policymakers talked about how they were going to have to raise rates soon, but they didn’t do it until March of 2022. They were constrained by the earlier guidance they had provided. I think they’ll be careful to not get in that sort of bind again.

And, when interest rates were stuck at the lower bound and the Fed was already buying securities and wanted more monetary accommodation to support the economy, policymakers provided guidance. Basically, they said, “We’re not going to raise rates until we reach maximum employment. We’re going to allow the economy to get going, and maybe even get going fairly strongly, before we raise rates.”

That lets businesses say, “OK, we’d better invest so that we can manage demand when it picks up.” That supported immediate spending, which is helpful for the economy when it’s in a hole and stuck at the zero bound.

The Fed also deployed some additional unconventional tools used during the Global Financial Crisis, including central bank lending programs to banks and other financial firms, and it extended them to businesses and others.

At the same time, the government was providing assistance to the unemployed, sending checks to families, and so on. The cumulative effect, not just in the U.S. but around the world, was a faster recovery than people expected. The economy bounced back quickly.

Q: Quickly enough that we got inflation?

A number of factors contributed to inflation but most significant was how the pandemic disrupted supply chains. Here’s one example of how the problems compounded:

Everybody wanted to buy cars to get off mass transportation because of concern about COVID. They had a check from the government that could be used for a down payment. But cars require computer chips, and COVID outbreaks in various countries messed up computer chip manufacturing. Chip manufacturers couldn’t keep up with demand for chips, which meant auto production couldn’t keep up with demand for vehicles.

That scenario of strong demand and weak supply happened in segment after segment of the economy. It created big disruptions.

There were also disruptions in labor markets. You had unemployment in the service sector because people were not going to the gym; they were buying a Peloton. They weren’t going to the movies; they were buying a big-screen TV.

It’s always hard to move labor from one part of the economy to another. That was especially true during the pandemic. But the sectoral reallocation had to happen. You could see in labor market indicators that the labor market wasn’t working well for a while.

The cumulative effect of all of that was inflation starting in 2021.

Q: Many people thought the inflation would be transitory; it would fall as soon as supply chain disruptions resolved. Why didn’t that happen?

Partly, the supply disruptions were simply larger and lasted longer than expected. Partly, Russia went to war in Ukraine and messed up energy markets and commodity markets, broadly boosting inflation further in 2022.

Q: Who made the right call on responding to the inflation?

Many emerging market economies moved quickly. Their central banks didn’t have as much credibility. They hadn’t built it over time, so they felt they needed to respond quickly, and they did.

However, in a lot of advanced economies, including the U.S., the turn was much slower. The Fed was initially thinking, “The supply chain disruptions will pass. We don’t need to respond with strong monetary policy.” And that was a reasonable thing to be thinking at first. And they were confident that they had credibility with the public. They believed that high inflation wouldn’t get built into wage and price setting. That’s important to avoid because then it propagates itself forward and you have persistently high inflation.

In 2022, the main advanced-economy central banks realized that even if the inflation was in some sense the result of temporary factors, it was lasting a long time, and there was a real risk that the high inflation was going to get built into wage and price setting—so they were behind. They raised rates very rapidly. Inflation went to the highest levels we’d seen in 40 years, and interest rates then went up faster than we’d seen in about 40 years, to catch up.

Looking for more insights?Sign up to get our top stories by email. Email    

On the whole, the outcomes so far look surprisingly good. Last year, inflation in the United States came down pretty rapidly to around 3%. That’s above the Fed’s preferred level of inflation of around 2%, but it fell a long way back without a big recession.

The economy kind of normalized, the labor market normalized, supply chain disruptions passed. The really strong surge in demand softened in the face of tighter monetary policy and cumulatively that got inflation back to much more reasonable levels.

Q: What happens next?

It depends very much on whether households and businesses are confident inflation is going to come back to 2%. If they are, then they build that into wage contracts, they build that into pricing, and inflation comes gradually back to 2% over the next year or so.

But if this high inflation period was enough to boost the ambient level of inflation to a level like 3%, there may need to be a much slower economy for a while to get inflation back down to 2%.

Late last year, the Fed was reasonably optimistic about the outlook for inflation, and policymakers began talking about when would be the right time to start easing policy. They were hoping for a “soft landing,” where growth would slow to a sustainable pace, and inflation would come down to target. However, the economic data this year have suggested a stronger economy and higher inflation than the Fed anticipated. That has led policymakers to push back on the timing of policy easing—it’s possible the Fed won’t ease policy at all this year, but just wait to give the current tight monetary policy more time to work. All along, the Fed has said that the outlook is very uncertain, and that was right!

Q: How did the response to inflation compare to previous efforts?

In the 1970s, oil and commodity price shocks sent inflation up a lot. The Fed and other central banks didn’t do a good job that time and the inflation became a persistent problem. It took a massive recession in the early ’80s, when the Fed chair was Paul Volcker, to get inflation back down to more reasonable levels. And it didn’t get back to 2% until the ’90s.

Being aware of that history, Fed policymakers knew that if they blew it, it would be very costly. They saw two risks. One, we do too much and cause a recession that’s not really necessary to bring inflation down. Two, we don’t do enough. Inflation stays high and it gets built into wage and price setting. They saw that second risk as much worse because if that happens, you eventually have to have a much bigger recession to get inflation back under control.

Q: Did the delay in the Fed’s response matter?

I don’t think it was a very expensive mistake. If they had raised rates gradually in late ’21, when the situation was less bad, rather than raise them really fast in March, which is what they did, the macroeconomic consequences wouldn’t have been very different.

One lesson they are likely to take away from this period is that they got constrained by their own guidance. By the fall of 2021, it was clear inflation was lasting, so the Fed had a choice. Policymakers could say, “Yes, we said we wouldn’t raise rates until we reached maximum employment, but the situation is different now” and raise rates. Or they could stick with the earlier guidance. They chose to do the latter. They talked about how they were going to have to raise rates soon, but they didn’t do it until March of 2022. That was just late.

So they were constrained by themselves—by the guidance they had provided. That was unfortunate. I think they’ll be careful to not get in that sort of bind again.

Q: Has our understanding of how monetary policy should respond to inflation changed in the last few years?

Going forward, I think central banks will say, “We need to be flexible about responding to inflation. And we want to be more symmetrical than we might have been going into 2020.” That’s one lesson from the events of the last few years. When the economy was really weak after the financial crisis, and inflation stayed low for a number of years, some central banks decided that high inflation wasn’t something to worry about and they needed to be more aggressive about responding to low inflation.

That came about because inflation was 2%, plus or minus, from the mid-’90s until 2020. If the economy got a little bit hot or cold, it didn’t really have an effect on inflation. If there were shocks—something happened in the Middle East and oil prices went up—there was higher inflation for a while, but people just kind of looked through that, and it came back down. What central bankers say is, inflation expectations became really well anchored. If you’re a central bank, that’s terrific. You’ve built a lot of credibility. Everybody believes you.

But then we got the biggest supply shocks we’ve experienced since the 1970s because of the pandemic and the war in Ukraine. Suddenly we had an inflation problem of a sort that we hadn’t had in decades. The Fed understood the lessons from the 1970s; they did respond, maybe with a lag, but they did respond effectively. And I think the awareness of the need to respond to high or low inflation will remain.

Q: What else has changed about our understanding of inflation?

I remember people saying things like, “You need a 7.5% unemployment rate for two years to get inflation back down.” Those assessments were looking back to what happened in the 1970s. The thing is, back then the Fed didn’t have as much credibility. It didn’t keep inflation expectations well anchored. Because of that, inflation got out of hand, and it took a big recession to get it back down again.

This time, even as it was raising rates, the Fed made a fundamental judgment call. Policymakers believed that because this inflation largely had to do with temporary supply disruptions and temporary effects of higher commodity prices—which really did pass—then, as long as the economy doesn’t overheat, the labor market doesn’t get too tight, and inflation expectations remain reasonably anchored around 2%, we don’t need to have a huge recession to bring inflation down. They believed a soft landing was a real possibility.

A very tight labor market and overheating economy accounted for about 1% of the current inflation. And that 1% may be a more troubling kind of underlying inflation that may be harder to get rid of.

However, there’s also a possibility that the economy will have to slow more to get inflation all the way back down to 2%. There’s a paper I really like by my old boss, Ben Bernanke, and Olivier Blanchard on what drove the inflation in the U.S. over the last few years. Their bottom line is that the temporary supply disruptions and commodity price shocks pushed inflation up for a time. That transitory inflation went up and came down. But, in addition, the economy did overheat for a while. The labor market was really tight in part because it was so dislocated as a result of the pandemic. Businesses had huge vacancy numbers. They couldn’t hire enough workers. Wages went up a lot.

Bernanke and Blanchard argue that period of a very tight labor market and overheating economy accounted for about 1% of the current inflation. And that 1% may be a more troubling kind of underlying inflation that may be harder to get rid of.

We don’t know if they’re right or not. If they are, the economy may need to slow further for a time, just enough to get a little slack in labor and goods markets and help bring inflation down. The unemployment rate is currently 3.8%, and the Fed estimates the long-run normal level of the unemployment rate to be around 4%. Maybe the unemployment rate will have to rise above 4%—some people might even say to 5%. I don’t think anybody’s saying 7.5% anymore. That analysis just looks wrong now.

Most of the inflation was transitory. It came, it went, but there is this underlying bit of inflation that may be more costly to bring down. And whether or not we get a truly soft landing or not depends on how that plays out. As some have said, the “last mile” of the disinflation may be the hardest.

Q: What’s the difference between 2% inflation and 3%?

There’s a huge debate in the literature about why 2% should be the target, why not 1%, why not 3%, why not 4%? Without getting into the details of that, the Fed’s reasoning is that a 2% inflation rate best balances their dual mandate of achieving maximum employment and stable prices.

Two percent is a bit higher than what you might think of as consistent with price stability, but that little bit more kind of lubricates price setting and wage setting, which helps the Fed to better achieve the maximum employment part of the mandate.

If they just stopped at 3% and declared that the new target, I think inflation expectations would come unanchored. Maybe expectations would eventually end up well anchored at 3%, but it would take a while, and there would be costs. Nobody wants to take that chance.

I think they want to continue to aim for 2% over the next few years. If, later this year, they found themselves with an inflation rate around 3%, an unemployment rate around 4%, and the economy chugging along, I’m not sure that they would want to set out to cause a recession to bring inflation down from 3% to 2%. They might operate with slightly tight monetary policy and figure very gradually over time they’ll move inflation down. But that would be a really hard call for the policymakers, and if they end up in that situation, it’ll be interesting to see what they say.

n
nancyjin5391
没说因为与中国decoupling?
米奇的厨房
是啊,Covid是一个因素,石油价格是另外一个重要因素。只要石油价格低,其他的因素影响有限
B
BrightLine
看看原因如下:

造成美国自2020年以后通胀的原因主要包括以下几个方面:

1. 疫情影响与财政刺激

新冠疫情导致经济大规模停摆,美国政府采取了多轮财政刺激政策,包括直接向居民发放现金支票、大规模失业救济以及企业纾困。这些措施大幅增加了市场的货币供给,刺激了消费需求。

2. 供应链中断

疫情引发的全球供应链危机使得商品供应不足,特别是关键原材料和芯片短缺,导致生产成本上升,推高了商品价格。

3. 劳动力短缺与工资上涨

疫情期间大量劳动者退出劳动市场,劳动力供给减少导致工资上涨,进一步加剧了通胀压力。

4. 能源价格上涨

全球能源需求复苏与地缘政治冲突(如俄乌战争)导致能源价格飙升,尤其是原油和天然气价格上涨,对美国的物价水平产生了连锁反应。

5. 宽松的货币政策

为应对疫情冲击,美联储采取了超低利率政策并进行大规模资产购买。这种宽松的货币政策在短期内提振了经济,但也为通胀埋下隐患

6. 消费需求激增

随着疫情逐步缓解,消费者报复性消费和积累的储蓄大量释放,进一步加剧了需求端的通胀压力。

h
hhtt
新冠是个很大的起因,但是以后最主要的是油价,和九叔大撒钱,加上联储对通涨的反应。
P
Pilot007
对照中美就知道为啥了,美国疫情期间不断给民众发钱,中国把民众都封起来。疫情后一个发钱太多通胀,一个被封久了害怕,萧条
加州阳光123
里面也提到了第一个原因是labor cost 的急剧上升

To answer these questions, the authors break down the headline inflation number into two categories: core inflation and deviations from the core inflation number. Core inflation is the level of slack or tightness in the labor market. Deviations from the core inflation number are the large changes in the price of a good or service in a particular industry. These deviations can also be unexpected inflation shocks to the headline inflation figure. These shocks can then lead to a pass-through inflation increase to core inflation.

As the labor market tightened during 2021 and 2022, core inflation rose as the ratio of job vacancies to unemployment increased. This ratio is used to measure wage pressures that then pass through to the prices for goods and services. As workers bargain for better pay, firms begin to increase prices. So, from this research, the authors find that three main components explain the rise in inflation since 2020: volatility of energy prices, backlogs of work orders for goods and service caused by supply chain issues due to COVID-19, and price changes in the auto-related industries.

越王剑
按照芝加哥派经济学理论,造成通胀主要是两个原因

第一,货币大量增发。这是疫情之后确实发生的。川普拜登共同怎发了大量货币。尤其是疫情后期,已经不需要lock down的时候仍然封禁和增发货币

第二,工资超过生产力,使企业不得不提价。这也是疫情中发生的。疫情开始后,各公司为了线上能力以高价雇佣了大量员工。比如亚马逊,严重超载。这也是今年硅谷大裁员的原因之一。因为疫情时给的工资太高。

在经济学流派里,还没有提过关税导致通胀。

因为关税是一次性加到位,不会持续的提升。各公司也有方法绕过关税。关税对通胀的影响不大。绝对不是主要原因。

川普的计划也很明显,对外加关税也是为了他的减税计划。不然减税钱从哪里来?

但是正象一郎所言,关税不是万能的。应该适可而止。

三心三意
还有供应链被打乱,影响成本
加州阳光123
关税是有影响的,记得那时

对中国家具增收25%的关税,本来是0,一下子家具的价格就涨了不少,当然供应商也不傻,马上在柬埔寨,越南和马来西亚开厂逃避关税,但是物价照样上涨,因为运费和供应链不稳定。

疫情期间,国际海运费上涨,导致很多商品到货延晚,美国零售商的货架上空空如也,谁也没料到会断供,于是买手就开始比原计划多订货,提早交货以应付由于疫情导致的生产周期延长和船运周期延长,这样买手不会爱剋或被炒鱿鱼,所以21年22年我们订单接到手软,来不及做,导致最近一两年零售商都在清仓,采购订单数量减少,这些大家不知道,但是我们是非常清楚零售行业的动向的。

米奇的厨房
是的,Covid这个突然事件的影响也是不小的。
越王剑
疫情毕竟不会每年都有

今后数年将更加趋于正常。不稳定因素就是两场战争。如果战争能停止,我们就不必担心象疫情期间一样的通胀。能否止战是对川普的巨大考验。牛逼吹出去了不能没个交代。哈哈

加州阳光123
停战是可能的,但是如他夸下的海口降低2T开销我持怀疑态度
米奇的厨房
对啊,油价是根本,很多人不明白,大部分生活用品都和油价有很直接的关系,不是直接石油的副产品,也是副产品的副产品

油价一涨,万物都会涨,何况运输还是靠油啊。

九叔的这个所谓的环保绿色经济很成问题,不是不要环保,而是不能脱离现实的搞。要不是他自己砍了自己的脚停止页岩油的生产,油价不会这么高,俄罗斯也不会这么有钱的打仗。拿着环保要求去和中国政府谈判,就是与虎谋皮,白给啊

P
Pilot007
估计现在正在紧锣密鼓的捣腾司机和普金,否则上任一天就搞定的牛皮吹破了就不好了。哈哈
秋前
对! 你说的靠谱!
越王剑
川普第一任前三年就有关税

如果不是疫情突发,真不一定引起大通胀。

不过现在争论也无用, 四目以待吧,市场经常是出人预料。

米奇的厨房
好像是两边威胁,必须坐到谈判桌子上来,誰不上来就给对方大杀器或者优先权利。
越王剑
这个牛逼吹的太大,我认为没戏。哈哈

在明天终能停战就算他牛逼。

他鄉之客
我認為有兩個原因,
米奇的厨房
司机也是个很硬的脖子,不那么好对付的,不过乌克兰毕竟国力小,没有美国支持,是撑不下去的
越王剑
把戈尔的一T绿色能源计划砍掉就出来一半。

砍他一半都不嫌多。

他鄉之客
柬埔寨,越南和马来西亚的家具只要不比中國貴就有市場, 不須要比中國便宜. 如果你是老闆, 也不會減價.
P
Pilot007
城头新闻说司机已经退一步了,领土不要但要北约提供安全保护
米奇的厨房
希望能谈成别打了,都死了几十万人了
加州阳光123
柬埔寨,越南和马来的家具比中国贵也有市场,因为少了25%的关税,所以他们也是不赚白不赚

举例:如果中国一个餐桌的成本是80块的话,加了25%的关税就是100块,其他三个国家如果真实成本是60块的话,他们可以报90-95块也可以,因为是零关税,生意场上没人傻。

他鄉之客
沒錯, 用妳的例子, 他們也會賣100塊.不會少. 因為中國關
他鄉之客
稅可能再漲高於25%. 這是不確定因素.
n
nancyjin5391
2008年后,也是大撒币,可当时并没有引起通膨